Traffic congestion

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to: navigation, search
Congestion on a Prestes Maia Avenue in São Paulo.
Congestion on a Prestes Maia Avenue in São Paulo.
Congestion on a city road in Moscow.
Congestion on a city road in Moscow.

Traffic congestion is a condition on any network as use increases and is characterized by slower speeds, longer trip times, and increased queueing. The most common example is the physical use of roads by vehicles. When traffic demand is great enough that the interaction between vehicles slows the speed of the traffic stream, congestion is incurred. As demand approaches the capacity of a road (or of the intersections along the road), extreme traffic congestion sets in. When vehicles are fully stopped for periods of time, this is colloquially known as a traffic jam.

Contents

[edit] Definition

[edit] Causes

Congestion caused by a road accident, Algarve, Portugal.
Congestion caused by a road accident, Algarve, Portugal.
Congestion caused by evacuees fleeing Hurricane Rita. Traffic in all lanes of the highway is traveling in the same direction.
Congestion caused by evacuees fleeing Hurricane Rita. Traffic in all lanes of the highway is traveling in the same direction.

Traffic congestion occurs when a volume of traffic or modal split generates demand for space greater than the available road capacity. There are a number of specific circumstances which cause or aggravate congestion; most of them reduce the capacity of a road at a given point or over a certain length, or increase the number of vehicles required for a given throughput of people or goods. A 2005 U.S. study stated that there are seven root causes of congestion, and gives the following summary of their contributions: bottlenecks 40%, traffic incidents 25%, bad weather 15%, work zones 10%, poor signal timing 5%, and special events/other 5%.[1] Other causes include conditions where the mode share between high and low occupancy vehicles primarily consists of low occupancy vehicles or of types of vehicle that take up a large quantum of network space per person. Speed and flow can also affect network capacity though the relationship is complex.[citation needed]

Traffic research still cannot fully predict under which conditions a "traffic jam" (as opposed to heavy, but smoothly flowing traffic) may suddenly occur. It has been found that individual incidents (such as accidents or even a single car braking heavily in a previously smooth flow) may cause ripple effects which then spread out and create a sustained traffic jam when, otherwise, normal flow might have continued for some time longer.[2]

[edit] Mathematical theories

Some traffic engineers have attempted to apply the rules of fluid dynamics to traffic flow, likening it to the flow of a fluid in a pipe. Congestion simulations and real-time observations have shown that in heavy but free flowing traffic, jams can arise spontaneously, triggered by minor events ("butterfly effects"), such as an abrupt steering maneuver by a single motorist. Traffic scientists liken such a situation to the sudden freezing of supercooled fluid.[3] However, unlike a fluid, traffic flow is often affected by signals or other events at junctions that periodically affect the smooth flow of traffic; matrix entropy models consider the effects of this by "platooning" groups of vehicles and by randomising the flow patterns within individual segments of the network.

In Boris Kerner's three phase traffic theory, congestion is classified into two distinct phases: synchronised flow and wide moving jams (in addition to the first phase, free flow). In synchronised flow, the speeds of the vehicles are low and vary quite a lot between vehicles, but the traffic flow (expressed in vehicles per time unit) remains close to free flow. In wide moving jams, vehicle speeds are more equal and lower, and time delays can be quite large.

[edit] Economic theories

Congested roads can be seen as an example of the tragedy of the commons. Because roads in most places are free at the point of usage, there is little financial incentive for drivers not to over-utilize them, up to the point where traffic collapses into a jam, when demand becomes limited by opportunity cost. Privatization of highways and road pricing have both been proposed as measures that may reduce congestion through economic incentives and disincentives. Congestion can also happen due to non-recurring highway incidents, such as a crash or roadworks, which may reduce the road's capacity below normal levels.

Economist Anthony Downs, in his books Stuck in Traffic (1992) and Still Stuck in Traffic (2004), offers a dissenting view: rush hour traffic congestion is inevitable because of the benefits of having a relatively standard work day. In a capitalist economy, goods can be allocated either by pricing (ability to pay) or by queueing (first-come first-serve); congestion is an example of the latter. Instead of the traditional solution of making the "pipe" large enough to accommodate the total demand for peak-hour vehicle travel (a supply-side solution), either by widening roadways or increasing "flow pressure" via automated highway systems, Downs advocates greater use of road pricing to reduce congestion (a demand-side solution, effectively rationing demand), in turn plowing the revenues generated therefrom into public transportation projects. Road pricing itself is controversial, more information is available in the dedicated article.

[edit] Classification

Qualitative classification of traffic is often done in the form of a six letter A-F level of service (LOS) scale defined in the Highway Capacity Manual, a US document used (or used as a basis for national guidelines) worldwide. These levels are used by transportation engineers as a shorthand and to describe traffic levels to the lay public. While this system generally uses delay as the basis for its measurements, the particular measurements and statistical methods vary depending on the facility being described. For instance, while the percent time spent following a slower-moving vehicle figures into the LOS for a rural two-lane road, the LOS at an urban intersection incorporates such measurements as the number of drivers forced to wait through more than one signal cycle.[4]

[edit] Negative impacts

Traffic congestion detector in Germany.
Traffic congestion detector in Germany.

Traffic congestion has a number of negative effects:

  • Wasting time of motorists and passengers ("opportunity cost"). As a non-productive activity for most people, congestion reduces regional economic health.
  • Delays, which may result in late arrival for employment, meetings, and education, resulting in lost business, disciplinary action or other personal losses.
  • Inability to forecast travel time accurately, leading to drivers allocating more time to travel "just in case", and less time on productive activities.
  • Wasted fuel increases air pollution and carbon dioxide emissions contributing to global warming owing to increased idling, acceleration and braking. Increased fuel use may also in theory cause a rise in fuel costs.
  • Wear and tear on vehicles as a result of idling in traffic and frequent acceleration and braking, leading to more frequent repairs and replacements.
  • Stressed and frustrated motorists, encouraging road rage and reduced health of motorists.
  • Emergencies: blocked traffic may interfere with the passage of emergency vehicles traveling to their destinations where they are urgently needed.
  • Spillover effect from congested main arteries to secondary roads and side streets as alternative routes are attempted ('rat running'), which may affect neighborhood amenity and real estate prices.

[edit] Countermeasures

It has been suggested by some commentators[who?] that the level of congestion that society tolerates is a rational (though not necessarily conscious) choice between the costs of improving the transportation system (in infrastructure or management) and the benefits of quicker travel. Others[who?] link it largely to subjective lifestyle choices, differentiating between car-owning and car-free households.

[edit] Road infrastructure

  • Junction improvements
  • Reversible lanes, where certain sections of highway operate in the opposite direction on different times of the day/ days of the week, to match asymmetric demand. This may be controlled by Variable-message signs or by movable physical separation
  • Separate lanes for specific user groups (usually with the goal of higher people throughput with fewer vehicles)

[edit] Urban planning and design

City planning and urban design practices can have a huge impact on levels of future traffic congestion, though they are of limited relevance for short-term change.

  • Grid plans including Fused Grid road network geometry, rather than tree-like network topology which branches into cul-de-sacs (which reduce local traffic, but increase total distances driven and discourage walking by reducing connectivity). This avoids concentration of traffic on a small number of arterial roads and allows more trips to be made without a car.
  • Zoning laws that encourage mixed-use development, which reduces distances between residential, commercial, retail, and recreational destinations (and encourage cycling and walking).
  • Carfree cities, car-light cities, and eco-cities designed to eliminate the need to travel by car for most inhabitants.[5][6]
  • Transit-oriented development are residential and commercial areas designed to maximize access to public transport.

[edit] Supply and demand

See also: Transportation Demand Management
Widening works underway on the M25 motorway to increase the number of lanes.
Widening works underway on the M25 motorway to increase the number of lanes.

Congestion can be reduced by either increasing road capacity (supply), or by reducing traffic (demand). Capacity can be increased in a number of ways, but needs to take account of latent demand otherwise it may be used more strongly than anticipated. Critics of the approach of adding capacity have compared it to "fighting obesity by letting out your belt" (inducing demand that did not exist before).[7][8] Reducing road capacity has in turn been attacked as removing free choice as well as increasing travel costs and times.

Increased supply can include:

  • Adding more capacity at bottlenecks (such as by adding more lanes at the expense of hard shoulders or safety zones, or by removing local obstacles like bridge supports and widening tunnels)
  • Adding more capacity over the whole of a route (generally by adding more lanes)
  • Creating new routes
  • Traffic management improvements (see separate section below)

Reduction of demand can include:

  • Parking restrictions, making motor vehicle use less attractive by increasing the monetary and non-monetary costs of parking, introducing greater competition for limited city or road space.[9] Most transport planning experts agree that free parking distorts the market in favour of car travel, exacerbating congestion.[10][11]
  • Park and ride facilities allowing parking at a distance and allowing continuation by public transport or ride sharing. Park-and-ride car parks are commonly found at metro stations, freeway entrances in suburban areas, and at the edge of smaller cities.
  • Reduction of road capacity to force traffic onto other travel modes. Methods include traffic calming and the shared space concept.
  • Road pricing, charging money for access onto a road/specific area at certain times, congestion levels or for certain road users
    • "Cap and trade", in which only licensed cars are allowed on the roads.[12] A limited quota of car licences are issued each year and traded in a free market fashion. This guarantees that the number of cars does not exceed road capacity while avoiding the negative effects of shortages normally associated with quotas. However since demand for cars tends to be inelastic, the result are exorbitant purchase prices for the licenses, pricing out the lower levels of society, as seen Singapore's Certificate of Entitlement scheme.[13]
    • Congestion pricing, where a certain area, such as the inner part of a congested city, is surrounded with a cordon into which entry with a car requires payment. The cordon may be a physical boundary (i.e., surrounded by toll stations) or it may be virtual, with enforcement being via spot checks or cameras on the entry routes. Major examples are Singapore's electronic road pricing, the London congestion charge system, and the Stockholm congestion tax.
  • Road space rationing, where regulatory restrictions prevent certain types of vehicles from driving under certain circumstances or in certain areas.
    • Number plate restrictions based on days of the week, as practiced in several large cities in the world, such as Athens,[14] Mexico City and São Paulo.[15] In effect, such cities are banning a different part of the automobile fleet from roads each day of the week. Mainly introduced to combat smog, these measures also reduce congestion. A weakness of this method is that richer drivers can purchase a second or third car to circumvent the ban.[citation needed]
    • Permits, where only certain types of vehicles (such as residents) are permitted to enter a certain area, and other types (such as through-traffic) are banned.[15] For example, Bertrand Delanoe, the mayor of Paris, has proposed to impose a complete ban on motor vehicles in the city's inner districts, with exemptions only for residents, businesses, and the disabled.[16]
  • Policy approaches, which usually attempt to provide either strategic alternatives or which encourage greater usage of existing alternatives through promotion, subsidies or restrictions.

[edit] Traffic management

Use of so-called Intelligent transportation system, which guide traffic:

[edit] Other associated

  • School opening times arranged to avoid peak hour traffic (in some countries, private car school pickup and drop-off traffic are substantial percentages of peak hour traffic).[citation needed]
  • Considerate driving behaviour promotion and enforcement. Driving practices such as tailgating and frequent lane changes can reduce a road's capacity and exacerbate jams. In some countries signs are placed on highways to raise awareness, while others have introduced legislation against inconsiderate driving.
  • Visual barriers to prevent drivers from slowing down out of curiosity (often called "rubbernecking" in the United States). This often includes accidents, with traffic slowing down even on roadsides physically separated from the crash location. This also tends to occur at construction sites, which is why some countries have introduced rules that motorway construction has to occur behind visual barrier
  • Speed limit reductions, as practiced on the M25 motorway in London. With lower speeds allowing cars to drive closer together, this increases the capacity of a road. Note that this measure is only effective if the interval between cars is reduced, not the distance itself. Low intervals are generally only safe at low speeds.
  • Lane splitting/filtering, where space-efficient vehicles, usually motorcycles and scooters, ride or drive in the space between cars, buses, and trucks. This is however illegal in many countries, being perceived as a safety risk.[28]

[edit] By country

[edit] Brazil

Typical traffic jam in São Paulo downtown, despite road space rationing by plate number. Rua da Consolação, São Paulo, Brasil.
Typical traffic jam in São Paulo downtown, despite road space rationing by plate number. Rua da Consolação, São Paulo, Brasil.

In Brazil the recent records of traffic jams over the major big cities are recognized by public authorities as one of the main challenges for São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro, Belo Horizonte, Brasilia, Curitiba and Porto Alegre, where due to the country's economic bonanza, the automobile fleets have almost doubled in several of these cities from 2000 to 2008.

According to Time Magazine, São Paulo has the world's worst traffic jams.[29] In 2008, the accumulated tailbacks have reached in average more than 120 miles (190 km) during rush hours, and on May 9, 2008, the historical record was set with 166 miles (266 km) of accumulated queues out of 522 mi (835 km) being monitored.[30] Despite implementation since 1997 of road space rationing by the last digit of the plate number during rush hours every weekday, traffic in this 20 million city still experiences severe congestion. According to experts, this is due to the accelerated rate of motorization occurring since 2003, in São Paulo the fleet is growing at a rate of 7.5% per year, with almost 1.000 new cars bought in the city every day, and the limited capacity of public transport. The subway has only 38 miles of lines, though 22 further miles are under construction or planned by 2010. Every day, many citizens spend between three up to four hours behind the wheel. In order to mitigate the aggravating congestion problem, since June 30, 2008 the road space rationing program was expanded to include and restrict trucks and light commercial vehicles.[31][32]

[edit] New Zealand

New Zealand has followed strongly car-oriented transport policies since after World War II (especially in the Auckland area, where about one-third of the county's population lives),[33] and currently has one of the highest car-ownership rates per capita in the world, after the United States.[34] Because of the negative results, congestion in the big centres is a major problem. Current measures include both the construction of new road infrastructure as well as increased investment in public transport, which had strongly declined in all cities of the country except Wellington.

[edit] United Kingdom

In the United Kingdom the inevitability of congestion in some urban road networks has been officially recognised since the Department for Transport set down policies based on the report Traffic in Towns in 1963:

Even when everything that it is possibly to do by way of building new roads and expanding public transport has been done, there would still be, in the absence of deliberate limitation, more cars trying to move into, or within our cities than could possibly be accommodated.[35].

The Department for Transport sees growing congestion as one of the most serious transport problems facing the UK.[36] On 1 December 2006, Rod Eddington published a UK government-sponsored report into the future of Britain's transport infrastructure. The Eddington Transport Study set out the case for action to improve road and rail networks, as a "crucial enabler of sustained productivity and competitiveness". Eddington has estimated that congestion may cost the economy of England £22 bn a year in lost time by 2025. He warned that roads were in serious danger of becoming so congested that the economy would suffer.[37] At the launch of the report Eddington told journalists and transport industry representatives introducing road pricing to encourage drivers to drive less was an "economic no-brainer". There was, he said "no attractive alternative". It would allegedly cut congestion by half by 2025, and bring benefits to the British economy totalling £28 bn a year.[38]

On Fridays in California, Interstate 5 is often congested as Los Angeles residents travel north for the weekend.
On Fridays in California, Interstate 5 is often congested as Los Angeles residents travel north for the weekend.

[edit] United States

In the United States, construction of new highway capacity has not kept pace with increases in population and car use and the resulting increase in demand for highway travel. Between 1980 and 1999, the total length of highways as measured by miles increased by only 1.5 percent,[citation needed] while the total number of miles of vehicle travel increased by 76 percent.[39]

The Texas Transportation Institute estimates that in 2000 the 75 largest metropolitan areas experienced 3.6 billion vehicle-hours of delay, resulting in 5.7 billion US gallons (21.6 billion liters) in wasted fuel and $67.5 billion in lost productivity, or about 0.7% of the nation's GDP. It also estimates that the annual cost of congestion for each driver is approximately $1,000 in very large cities and $200 in small cities. Traffic congestion is increasing in major cities, and delays are becoming more frequent in smaller cities and rural areas.

In 2005, the three areas in the United States with the highest levels of traffic congestion were Los Angeles, New York and Chicago. The congestions cost for Los Angeles alone was estimated at US$ 9.325 billion.[40]

[edit] See also

[edit] References

  1. ^ "Traffic Congestion and Reliability: Trends and Advanced Strategies for Congestion Mitigation". U.S. Federal Highway Administration (2005-09-01). Retrieved on 2008-02-28.
  2. ^ Science Hobbyist: Traffic Waves (from the 'Science Hobbyist' website)
  3. ^ Critical Mass - Ball, Philip, ISBN 0-09-945786-5
  4. ^ Traffic Engineering, Third Edition. Roger P. Roess, Elana S. Prassas, and William R. McShane. ISBN 0-13-142471-8
  5. ^ British to help China build 'eco-cities' - The Observer, November 6 2005
  6. ^ Wired, Pop-Up Cities: China Builds a Bright Green Metropolis, 04.24.07
  7. ^ Dreaming of a Clean Car? - Kay, Jane Holtz, journalist and author
  8. ^ 2005 Mayors Luncheon (from the NAIOP website, Tampa Bay, United States)
  9. ^ Hermann Knoflacher (2006). "A new way to organize parking: the key to a successful sustainable transport system for the future". Environment and Urbanization 18 (2): 387–400. International Institute for Environment and Development. doi:10.1177/0956247806069621. 
  10. ^ Shoup, Donald C. (2005). The High Cost of Free Parking. American Planning Association. ISBN 1884829988. 
  11. ^ Knoflacher, Hermann [January 2001]. Stehzeuge. Der Stau ist kein Verkehrsproblem. (in German). Vienna: Böhlau. ISBN 978-3205989882. 
  12. ^ Goddard, Haynes (July 1997). "Using Tradeable Permits to Achieve Sustainability in the World's Large Cities". Environmental and Resource Economics 10 (1): 63–99. Springer Netherlands. doi:10.1023/A:1026444113237. 
  13. ^ The high cost of motoring in Singapore - Toh, Rex S., Business Horizons, March-April, 1994
  14. ^ "LEDA Measure: License plate based traffic restrictions, Athens, Greece". LEDA database. Retrieved on 2008-04-09.
  15. ^ a b "Regulatory restrictions". KonSULT, the Knowledgebase on Sustainable Urban Land use and Transport. Institute for Transport Studies, University of Leeds. Retrieved on 2008-04-20.
  16. ^ Henley, Jon (2005-03-15). "Paris drive to cut traffic in centre by 75%", The Guardian, London: Guardian Media Group. 
  17. ^ Simon, Hermann; Robert J Dolan. "Price Customization" (in English). Marketing Management 7 (3). American Marketing Association. 
  18. ^ Andersen, Bjørn (January 1993). "A survey of the Swiss public transport system and policy". Transport Reviews 13 (1): 61–81. doi:10.1080/01441649308716835. 
  19. ^ Adrian May (2007-03-16). "The philosophy and practice of Taktfahrplan: a case-study of the East Coast Main Line" (Working Paper). Working Paper 579. Institute of Transport Studies, University of Leeds, Leeds, UK. Retrieved on 2008-04-27.
  20. ^ Ogilvie, David; Matt Egan, Val Hamilton, Mark Petticrew (2004-09-22). "Promoting walking and cycling as an alternative to using cars: systematic review". British Medical Journal 329 (7469): 763. BMJ Publishing Group. doi:10.1136/bmj.38216.714560.55. PMID 15385407. 
  21. ^ Rietveld, Piet; Vanessa Daniel (August 2004). "Determinants of bicycle use: do municipal policies matter?". Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice 38 (7): 531–550. Elsevier. doi:10.1016/j.tra.2004.05.003. 
  22. ^ "Cycling in the Netherlands" (in English). Rijkswaterstaat (Dutch Ministry of Transport, Public Works and Water Management).
  23. ^ Matt Rosenberg (2007-09-26). "Slow But Steady "Telework Revolution" Eyed". Cascadia Prospectus. Retrieved on 2007-10-07.
  24. ^ "Motoring Towards 2050 – Roads and Reality". RAC foundation.
  25. ^ "Smarter Choices - Changing the way we travel". Department for Transport.
  26. ^ (December 2006) "New & Innovative Concepts for Helping European Transport Sustainability" in Niches Policy seminar., Committee of the Regions; Niches. 
  27. ^ WhyBike? (2006-03-06). "All the info you need on lanesharing (lanesplitting)".
  28. ^ Andrew Downie (2008-04-21). "The World's Worst Traffic Jams", Times Magazine. Retrieved on 2008-06-20. 
  29. ^ Congestionamento em SP atinge 266 km, maior índice da história
  30. ^ "Kassab restringe carga e descarga em SP e inclui caminhões no rodízio" (in Portuguese), Folha de São Paulo Online (2008-04-01). Retrieved on 2008-06-20. 
  31. ^ Folha de São Paulo (2008-06-18). "Kassab cria rodízio para caminhão no centro" (in Portuguese), INTELOG. Retrieved on 2008-06-20. 
  32. ^ Backtracking Auckland: Bureaucratic rationality and public preferences in transport planning - Mees, Paul; Dodson, Jago; Urban Research Program Issues Paper 5, Griffith University, April 2006
  33. ^ Modern Society (from Te Ara Encyclopedia of New Zealand. Accessed 2008-04-25.)
  34. ^ (1963/4) Traffic in Towns. Penguin Books in association with HMSO. 
  35. ^ "Tackling congestion on our roads". Department for Transport.
  36. ^ "Delivering choice and reliability". Department for Transport.
  37. ^ Rod Eddington (December 2006). "The Eddington Transport Study". UK Treasury.
  38. ^ Annual Vehicle Miles of Travel, Federal Highway Administration, 2003-02-14, <http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/onh00/graph1.htm>. Retrieved on 6 May 2007 
  39. ^ Table 2. Components of the Congestion Problem, 2005 Urban Area Totals (from the Texas Transportation Institute website. Accessed 2008-01-25.)

[edit] Further reading

  • R. Wiedemann, Simulation des Straßenverkehrsflusses. Schriftenreihe des IfV, 8, 1974. Institut für Verkehrswesen. Universität Karlsruhe. (In German language).
  • K. Nagel and M. Schreckenberg. A Cellular Automaton Model for Freeway Traffic. Journal de Physique I, 2:2221-2229, December 1992.
  • K. Nagel. High-speed Microsimulations of Traffic Flow. PhD thesis, Universität zu Köln, 1994. [1]
  • D. Chowdhury, L. Santen, and A. Schadschneider. Statistical Physics of Vehicular Traffic and Some Related Systems. Phys. Rep., 329:199-329, 2000. [2]
  • D. Helbing. Traffic and related self-driven many-particle systems. Rev. Mod. Phys., 73(4):1067-1141, 2001. [3]

[edit] External links

Wikimedia Commons has media related to:
Personal tools